Archive for September, 2009

Geriatrics and health reform

Monday, September 7th, 2009

The fastest growing segment of the US population is the elderly over the age of 85.

The fastest growing segment of the older population is the oldest old — that is, those ages 85 and older. They are projected to total 6 million as early as 2010, twice their 1990 level. Beginning in 2031, when the baby boomers will begin reaching 85, the number of oldest old will increase rapidly. The 85-and-over population is expected to grow fivefold, from 4 million in 2000 to 21 million by 2050.

This group is of particular concern to policymakers and planners because people ages 85 and older are more likely to be disabled than “young” elderly, ages 65 to 74.

In fact, I believe that the frail elderly, those over 85, are not the most expensive segment of the elderly to care for. They are the healthy portion of the population since those with poor genetic makeup or with bad habits are gone. They tend to be more fit than those with poor health, dementia and early death.

In 1995, I wrote a grant proposal to study the care of this elderly population by providing on-site care in assisted living facilities within an 8 mile radius of UCI medical center. Here are some basic data about Medicare beneficiaries in 1995. The changes since that time are chiefly a shift to the right in age in all studies.

In the fee for service sector of Medicare only 21% of beneficiaries used Part A services in 1995, although 84% of beneficiaries had Part B claims, indicating some covered medical service use. Median total expenditures per beneficiary were $884 per year in 1995, a modest amount indicating the small size of most claims. High expenditures are concentrated in a small percentile of the population. The top 2% of beneficiaries spend as much as the bottom 90% and the top 1% spend 19% of all Medicare expenditures. It is unusual for beneficiaries to remain in the very high expenditure group for more than one year. Patients in this category either die of an illness or recover after therapy and return to the low expenditure category. 47% of beneficiaries will be in the top quintile of expenditures for one year in a nine year study. 30% will be in the top decile for one year but only 10% are in the top decile for two or more years and only 1.2 % are in the top decile for four or more years. Mortality is high in this group and, for the beneficiaries who are in the top decile for two or more years, it exceeds 50% and is higher than that of the very high cost one year group. Individuals who have persistently high costs, while a very small group, account for a disproportionate share of expenditures. It is possible that multi-year high expenditures represent cases in which improved care could save substantial amounts of money. In addition, it is apparent that high cost Medicare beneficiaries, even in the un-managed fee for service sector, are a very small proportion of the total.

What about the frail elderly ? The group over age 85 ?

The frail elderly, usually described as those over age 85 and those with chronic illness, are estimated to comprise 10% of all Medicare beneficiaries. If all of the multi-year high cost beneficiaries were in this group it would still leave 88% of this group with costs close to the Average Annual Per Capita Cost over a multi-year span. It is unlikely that costs for this group exceed the average for other age groups and studies of end-of-life costs show a decline in costs after age 80 for decedents and after age 90 for survivors.

Remember this was 14 years ago. Our model was a demonstration project in San Francisco.

A program named On Lok began in San Francisco 25 years ago to care for frail elderly with low incomes, initially among the Chinese-American population of that city, and to keep them in their homes and out of nursing homes. It now operates five community service organizations in the city and has been the impetus for a national demonstration project called PACE (Program of All-inclusive Care for the Elderly). In 1983 On Lok became a dual capitation program funded by Medicare and Medicaid as an alternative to long term nursing home care which is covered, for Medicaid eligible individuals, by Medicaid. At present 15 PACE programs exist nationally as Medicare providers, 10 of which were mandated by OBRA in 1986 as a demonstration project (plus the five On Lok sites in San Francisco), and 40 sites are planned to be in operation next year. The program includes a four year demonstration project of up to 10 for-profit entities which, if successful, could qualify as permanent PACE providers. The PACE model includes a day care center which provides nursing care, case management, social activities, a nutrition program and respite for family care givers. Eligibility for the PACE program is income limited with a maximum income of $14,000 for individuals and $17,000 for married couples. It does not include pharmacy benefits but a new enhancement, called PACENET (Pharmaceutical Assistance Contract for the Elderly Needs Enhancement Tier) will cover drugs after a deductible ($500) and copayment ($8 for generic/ $15 for brands).

An independent evaluation by Abt Associates in 1995 was critical of the PACE model in several respects and suggested that the replication sites may be less successful than On Lok for a number of reasons. The catchment area of On Lok was only 2.5 square miles at initial development and is still less than 10 square miles after expansion. The replication sites have, in general, larger catchment areas and are located in communities with less population density than San Francisco. Another problem has been the slow growth of the replication sites’ client volume. Some of the reasons for slow growth include resistance to four or five day per week visits, the need to apply for Medicaid and the loss of choice of physician and other providers. Family support is necessary for this model to succeed and this varies among the replication sites. The report emphasizes that all sites exclude some eligible patients in spite of a need for expansion and this suggests that selection is occurring. This selection process is described as “niche marketing” or “skimming” in the report and the conclusion is that enthusiasm for the model among providers is greater than among clients.

The greatest change since these studies has to do with the growth of assisted living homes and home care. It is much, much easier to care for frail elderly at home than it was in 1986 or even in 1995. A second option was considered as a model.

A similar program, at the University of Pennsylvania, called CARE (Collaborative Assessment and Rehabilitation for Elders), has been established since 1993. It is certified as a CORF (Comprehensive Outpatient Rehabilitation Facility) and functions as a day hospital similar to the British day hospital. This program found that nursing, mental health, social work and care management services are not well reimbursed in a fee for service environment. Certification as a CORF improved reimbursement. Other limitations included relations with other providers who might feel competition, transportation, limitations on the services reimbursed by the CORF structure, cost of the day care facility and time limits of the CORF model. They are dependent on referral from primary care physicians and have no managed care patients. Patients are seen by Advanced Practice Nurses at intake and needs assessment is completed. Typical problems include poly-pharmacy, depression and cognition. Patients are seen in a “day hospital” for four hours per day, two to three times per week for an average of six weeks. Then the patients are returned to primary care physician follow-up and the CARE program has no long term follow-up.

Here again, there is a model for treating frail elderly with intensive short term care, usually correcting medication problems, assessing psychological issues and coaching family members on proper care. A third model was considered.

The Veterans Administration studied the effectiveness and efficiency of an outpatient Geriatric Evaluation and Management (GEM) program with a randomized trial comparing GEM patients and the usual primary care (UPC) population. This program was based on studies of inpatient geriatric units which had shown improved care. Other outpatient GEM studies had shown little evidence of efficacy of the concept, as measured by consumption of medical services. Tulloch and Moore, in Britain, showed increased number of admissions in GEM patients but reduced bed days and an increased use of social and health services with no difference in prevalence of health problems. The VA study showed significant improvement of health status and quality, as measured by the SF 20, and a significant improvement in survival. No significant differences in costs were reported in the original publication of the study although the GEM patients were seen twice as often.

If elderly patients are seen more frequently, and the problems that have affected them are solved, thereafter, they are less expensive to care for.

In a long term follow-up of the study a potential “investment effect” was identified in that, during the first 8 months of the program, GEM patients incurred 35% more health care cost than the UPC group but in the later stages, after one year, the ratio reversed with GEM patients’ costs being 38% less than the UPC group. This suggests the possibility that initial evaluation identified deferred health needs which, once corrected in the early stage of the study, resulted in less health care expenditures later. If this trend continues it may indicate that early correction of health problems results in less cost in the long term and may support the cost effectiveness of the GEM concept.. Both the GEM group and the control group showed improved health perception and functional status. This effect on the control group was attributed to the “study effect” first noted in the 1920s in efficiency measurement. Control patients responded to the increased attention of the study by improved status. The VA GEM study with long term follow-up has not been replicated and their patients were all male.

Due to an uncooperative medical center administrator, we were unable to conduct this study and prove our thesis; that the elderly have specific issues that, once solved, are no more expensive to care for than younger elderly patients and may, in fact, be less expensive. UCLA did a small scale study that was similar:

A similar study of geriatric assessment but this time performed at home was reported in 1995 by a group at UCLA. The patients were selected from voter rolls of the city of Santa Monica for age over 75 and 37% of those contacted by telephone agreed to participate. They were randomized to an intervention group and a Usual Care group. After a three year study period the intervention group were more able to live independently, less likely to require assistance and less likely to be in nursing homes long term. There was no difference in acute care hospital admissions and the intervention group had more hospital days per year and more physician visits per year than the control group. The principle benefit of the program seemed to be in the reduction of long term nursing home admissions.

Why is this important ? The over-85 elderly group is the fastest growing part of our population. There will be enormous resistance to any attempt to deny them care. The studies above mostly focused on “day hospitals” and intensive evaluation upon intake into the program. The evaluation may include a psychologist and a pharmacist, both of whom are concerned with common issues of depression and polypharmacy. Once these issues are dealt with, the elderly are easy to care for and the care will increasingly be delivered at home or in assisted living facilities.

At the moment, Medicare and the Obama administration do not seem to be focusing on these issues. This may mean that private options may become more important. Note that the common theme in all these studies is more frequent physician visits to these patients, whether they are at home or in day hospitals. Medicare is not only refusing to fund these more frequent visits but is threatening to prosecute physicians who see their elderly patents more frequently than the Medicare rules allow. For this reason, some geriatric physicians are dropping out of Medicare and practicing in a cash setting. The patients seem to be willing to pay for this additional care, suggesting that they and their family members perceive value.

This report discusses the future for Medicare without reform. There are several reforms that could be done without overt rationing. Some of them are discussed above.

Is the race card next ?

Monday, September 7th, 2009

The LA Times today has a story about Obama’s fall in the polls, but why is this the headline ?

Obama is fast losing white voters’ support

Since whites constitute, depending on your opinion of whether Latinos are white (I think so), the vast majority of the population, any significant drop in Obama’s poll numbers would be a drop in white voters’ support. Blacks, who constitute 13% of the population, are unlikely to change their support. Whites, including Hispanics, are 80% of the population and so will always be the group most represented in polls. Why the headline ?

Among white Democrats, Obama’s job approval rating has dropped 11 points since his 100-days mark in April, according to surveys by the Pew Research Center for the People and the Press. It has dropped by 9 points among white independents and whites over 50, and by 12 points among white women — all groups that will be targeted by both parties in next year’s midterm elections.

“While Obama has a lock on African Americans, his support among white voters seems to be almost in a free fall,” said veteran Republican pollster Neil Newhouse.

OK, that’s fair.

But the drop in support among whites also comes as some conservatives have stoked controversies that have the potential to further erode Obama’s standing among centrists — including some controversies that resulted from White House stumbles.

One such episode came to a head Sunday when Van Jones, Obama’s green jobs czar, resigned after a week of criticism over past inflammatory statements and for signing onto conspiracy theories questioning whether the U.S. government played a role in the Sept. 11 attacks. A White House official acknowledged Sunday that Jones had been vetted less rigorously than other officials.

Still fair.

In another episode, some conservatives have criticized a White House dinner invitation issued to the lead lawyer in the American Civil Liberties Union lawsuits that have forced the government to disclose Bush-era interrogation techniques. The lawyer was invited to an event for the Muslim holiday of Ramadan.

That’s a weird story and I have never heard of this. If I haven’t heard of it, I doubt many others have either.

These controversies have followed conspiracy theories that the president was born overseas and is ineligible to hold office, and that his true religion is Islam — false rumors that some Democrats worry could be affecting the public’s view of the president and his party.

That’s a fringe story and, I suspect, included to discredit the right for concerns, legitimate concerns, about Obama’s agenda. So far, I have seen no major issue described in the story and there have been plenty.

Pew first identified a slippage in white support immediately after a news conference in July, when Obama surprised many by saying that a white police officer had acted “stupidly” in arresting a black Harvard professor.

Now, we see one of the serious concerns arise. A president on national TV attacks a police officer without knowing any facts except the race of the two parties.

One black congressman, Rep. Charles B. Rangel (D-N.Y.), was quoted last week alleging that opposition to Obama’s healthcare policies was “a bias, a prejudice, an emotional feeling.”

“Some Americans have not gotten over the fact that Obama is president of the United States. They go to sleep wondering, ‘How did this happen?’ ” Rangel said, according to the New York Post.

Actually, I haven’t gotten over the fact that Rangel, like many senior members of the administration, doesn’t pay his taxes and gets away with it. Now, we get back to the heart of the story:

Democratic pollster David Beattie conducted a survey last month in one competitive congressional district that found that more than a quarter of independents believed Obama had not proven his natural-born status. The same sentiment was expressed by nearly 6 in 10 Republican women — a group that Beattie said would be important for a Democratic victory.

He declined to name the district because the polling was private, but said that such questions about Obama’s background seemed to be a “proxy” for voters’ growing unease with Obama’s ambitious agenda, which has included a potential push to create a government-sponsored health insurance plan.

This is utter BS but evidence of the plan to discredit criticism by linking it to fringe conspiracy theories.

More than half of whites older than 50 approved of Obama’s job performance in April. But now, after weeks of Republican accusations that the Democrats would seek to cut Medicare benefits, that number is 43%. Among white Democrats, Obama’s approval rating dropped to 78%, from 89%.

Some Democrats are hopeful that Republican opposition to Obama may be firing up core conservatives but failing to win over even skeptical centrists and independents to the GOP cause.

I don’t think it took Republicans to make the point that Obama plans Medicare cuts after he has talked about his grandmother’s hip replacement, which he thought a waste, and giving pain pills to an elderly woman instead of a pacemaker. The Democrats in the Senate committee considering the health reform legislation are talking about $500 billion in cuts. It doesn’t take Republicans to say this:

Baucus has declined to release details. But people involved in the talks said the plan would make more than $500 billion worth of changes to Medicare over the next decade, charging wealthy seniors more for prescription drug coverage, cutting $120 billion in payments to private insurance companies that serve some seniors and trimming projected payments to hospitals by $155 billion in an effort to spur efficiencies.

The Times seems to be turning over the race card as a strategy in case Obama doesn’t pull the rabbit out of the hat this week with his speech. I don’t think he will and I think they will turn more and more to these stories to discredit the criticism.

Democrat Economics

Thursday, September 3rd, 2009

Pete Stark has been in Congress far too long. Doubt that ? Watch this.

Amazing. No wonder they are happy to spend trillions on worthless bureaucrats. It is making us all rich !

UPDATE: He has lots of company among his fellow Democrats ! Just amazing.

Reagan, a great story

Thursday, September 3rd, 2009

I love this story about Ronald Reagan as president. It comes from Ted Kennedy’s upcoming memoir. I am just beginning the two volume set, Age of Reagan.

The senator said it had been difficult to get Reagan to focus on policy matters. He described a meeting with him that he and other senators had sought to press for shoe and textile import limits.

The senators were told that they would have just 30 minutes with the president. Reagan began the meeting, the book said, commenting on Mr. Kennedy’s shoes — asking if they were Bostonians — and then talking for 20 minutes about shoes and his experience selling shoes for his father. “Several of us began conspicuously to glance at our watches.” But to no avail. “And it was over!” Mr. Kennedy said. “No one got a word in about shoe or textile quota legislation.”

They had been rolled and it will become one more story of how dumb Reagan was. I love it. I wonder if, in those lucid and sober moments he had, Kennedy ever wondered if maybe Reagan knew exactly what he was doing when he genially stalled them until they ran out of time.

I will bet five dollars there are not five Democrats who will understand that story.

UPDATE: He did it to Republicans, too. He also said “There is no limit to what can be accomplished as long as it makes no difference who gets the credit.”

Health insurance

Wednesday, September 2nd, 2009

There is a rather emotional cover story in the Atlantic that has been linked to by several sources using it as an example of why US health care is collapsing and in need of reform. Some of these people either didn’t read the article or don’t understand it. Let’s read it.

But health insurance is different from every other type of insurance. Health insurance is the primary payment mechanism not just for expenses that are unexpected and large, but for nearly all health-care expenses. We’ve become so used to health insurance that we don’t realize how absurd that is. We can’t imagine paying for gas with our auto-insurance policy, or for our electric bills with our homeowners insurance, but we all assume that our regular checkups and dental cleanings will be covered at least partially by insurance. Most pregnancies are planned, and deliveries are predictable many months in advance, yet they’re financed the same way we finance fixing a car after a wreck—through an insurance claim.

This is exactly right and suggests one area for reform. Here is another true statement.

In designing Medicare and Medicaid in 1965, the government essentially adopted this comprehensive-insurance model for its own spending, and by the next year had enrolled nearly 12 percent of the population. And it is no coinci­dence that the great inflation in health-care costs began soon after. We all believe we need comprehensive health insurance because the cost of care—even routine care—appears too high to bear on our own. But the use of insurance to fund virtually all care is itself a major cause of health care’s high expense.

How about this ?

Well, for every two doctors in the U.S., there is now one health-insurance employee—more than 470,000 in total. In 2006, it cost almost $500 per person just to administer health insurance. Much of this enormous cost would simply disappear if we paid routine and predictable health-care expenditures the way we pay for everything else—by ourselves.

The people who are linking to this article are Obama supporters. have they read it ? Or just the title.

Now for some really radical statements:

Moral hazard has fostered an accidental collusion between providers benefiting from higher costs and patients who don’t fully bear them. In this environment, trying to control costs is awfully tough. When Medicare cut reimbursement rates in 2005 on chemotherapy and anemia drugs, for instance, it saved almost 20 percent of the previously billed costs. But Medicare’s total cancer-treatment costs actually rose almost immediately. As The New York Times reported, some physicians believed their colleagues simply performed more treatments, particularly higher-profit ones.

Want further evidence of moral hazard? The average insured American and the average uninsured American spend very similar amounts of their own money on health care each year—$654 and $583, respectively. But they spend wildly different amounts of other people’s money—$3,809 and $1,103, respectively. Sometimes the uninsured do not get highly beneficial treatments because they cannot afford them at today’s prices—something any reform must address. But likewise, insured patients often get only marginally beneficial (or even outright unnecessary) care at mind-boggling cost.

Some of this I agree with and some is a matter of understanding Jack Wennberg’s research on variation in health services. Across the country, those health services that are related to unanticipated incidents, like strokes and heart attacks and hip fractures, are about the same in frequency and expenditure. It is the services that are not clearly necessary or that have less clear indications that vary so much. An example widely discussed by Wennberg is prostate surgery for benign enlargement, or BPH. There is very little variation in prostate cancer except by race as blacks have a higher incidence.

This is a shocker for the lefties:

For fun, let’s imagine confiscating all the profits of all the famously greedy health-insurance companies. That would pay for four days of health care for all Americans. Let’s add in the profits of the 10 biggest rapacious U.S. drug companies. Another 7 days. Indeed, confiscating all the profits of all American companies, in every industry, wouldn’t cover even five months of our health-care expenses.

Now for some really shocking statements:

Every proposal for health-care reform has featured some element of cost control to “balance” the inflationary impact of expanding access. Yet it goes without saying that in the big picture, all government efforts to control costs have failed.

Why? One reason is a fixation on prices rather than costs. The government regularly tries to cap costs by limiting the reimbursement rates paid to providers by Medicare and Medicaid, and generally pays much less for each service than private insurers. But as we’ve seen, that can lead providers to perform more services, and to steer patients toward higher-priced, more lightly regulated treatments. The government’s efforts to expand “access” to care while limiting costs are like blowing up a balloon while simultaneously squeezing it. The balloon continues to inflate, but in misshapen form.

I have some doubts about that statement. I don’t think most doctors consciously choose to increase volume to make up for declining reimbursement but there may be an effect that is indirect. Medicare has chosen, for example, to cut payment for vascular surgery, such as the femoral popliteal bypass procedure that used to take me four to seven hours to do. Medicare now pays less than one-fourth what I was paid for this in 1990. The intent was to reduce the motivation of surgeons to operate, especially with big lengthy cases. There has been, at the same time, a trend to interventional radiology which is displacing vascular surgery. The catheter procedures, with stents and balloon angioplasties, are popular with patients because they don’t hurt as much as surgery. However, everything I know about the billing circumstances tells me that the money spent on angioplasties and stents and other radiology procedures is far more than the surgery procedures they replace. The surgeons aren’t happy about the trend but it is certainly not one of cost reduction.

Cost control is a feature of decentralized, competitive markets, not of centralized bureaucracy—a matter of incentives, not mandates. What’s more, cost control is dynamic. Even the simplest business faces constant variation in its costs for labor, facilities, and capital; to compete, management must react quickly, efficiently, and, most often, prospectively. By contrast, government bureaucracies set regulations and reimbursement rates through carefully evaluated and broadly applied rules. These bureaucracies first must notice market changes and resource misallocations, and then (sometimes subject to political considerations) issue additional regulations or change reimbursement rates to address each problem retrospectively.

Governments are slow and stupid. Yes, some of us knew that.

These bureaucracies first must notice market changes and resource misallocations, and then (sometimes subject to political considerations) issue additional regulations or change reimbursement rates to address each problem retrospectively.

As a result, strange distortions crop up constantly in health care. For example, although the population is rapidly aging, we have few geriatricians—physicians who address the cluster of common patient issues related to aging, often crossing traditional specialty lines. Why? Because under Medicare’s current reimbursement system (which generally pays more to physicians who do lots of tests and procedures), geriatricians typically don’t make much money. If seniors were the true customers, they would likely flock to geriatricians, bidding up their rates—and sending a useful signal to medical-school students. But Medicare is the real customer, and it pays more to specialists in established fields. And so, seniors often end up overusing specialists who are not focused on their specific health needs.

Not only doesn’t Medicare pay them well, it restricts their ability to care for their patients. I have previously posted on this. A huge consideration in controlling Medicare and end of life costs is home care. Yet, home care is very poorly paid and the number of visits is restricted.

Many reformers believe if we could only adopt a single-payer system, we could deliver health care more cheaply than we do today. The experience of other developed countries suggests that’s true: the government as single payer would have lower administrative costs than private insurers, as well as enormous market clout and the ability to bring down prices, although at the cost of explicitly rationing care.

But even leaving aside the effects of price controls on innovation and customer service, today’s Medicare system should leave us skeptical about the long-term viability of that approach. From 2000 to 2007, despite its market power, Medicare’s hospital and physician reimbursements per enrollee rose by 5.4 percent and 8.5 percent, respectively, per year. As currently structured, Medicare is a Ponzi scheme. The Medicare tax rate has been raised seven times since its enactment, and almost certainly will need to be raised again in the next decade. The Medicare tax contributions and premiums that today’s beneficiaries have paid into the system don’t come close to fully funding their care, which today’s workers subsidize. The subsidy is getting larger even as it becomes more difficult to maintain: next year there will be 3.7 working people for each Medicare beneficiary; if you’re in your mid-40s today, there will be only 2.4 workers to subsidize your care when you hit retirement age. The experience of other rich nations should also make us skeptical.

I really don’t think the Obama supporters read this article before recommending it. Medicare has to be reformed before tackling the rest of the system.

Another true statement:

Well, hospitals bill according to their price lists, but provide large discounts to major insurers. Individual consumers, of course, don’t benefit from these discounts, so they receive their bills at full list price (typically about 2.5 times the bill to an insured patient). Uninsured patients, however, pay according to how much of the bill the hospital believes they can afford (which, on average, amounts to 25 percent of the amount paid by an insured patient). Nonetheless, whatever discount a hospital gives to an uninsured patient is entirely at its discretion—and is typically negotiated only after the fact. Some uninsured patients have been driven into bankruptcy by hospital collections. American industry may offer no better example of pernicious “price discrimination,” nor one that entails greater financial vulnerability for American families.

One of my pet peeves is the secrecy of these discounts and this applies to Medicare as well with respect to physician payment. If I as a surgeon offer to perform a treatment at a cash price less than my “official fee” as determined by my Medicare profile, I am breaking the law. As a result, there is considerable upward pressure on doctors’ “retail” fees at the same time that Medicare is cutting the amount that is actually paid.

Most MRIs in this country are reimbursed by insurance or Medicare, and operate in the limited-competition, nontransparent world of insurance pricing. I don’t even know the price of many of the diagnostic services I’ve needed over the years—usually I’ve just gone to whatever provider my physician recommended, without asking (my personal contribution to the moral-hazard economy).

I don’t think he realizes that Medicare will penalize such a facility if it offers a cheaper price for a cash patient. This is a reason why medical IRAs are less useful than they might be. Unless the patient goes through the insurance company claims process, the discount that the insurance company has negotiated will not be obtained. Processing the claim, even though the insurance company will not pay it, costs money in administrative expense. That’s one reason for those 470,000 insurance employees. Far better would be a system in which actual prices were public knowledge and it made no difference if you were paying cash or the insurance company was paying. Then the medical IRA would be on the same terms as the insurance company and administrative costs would really go down.

By contrast, consider LASIK surgery. I still lack the (small amount of) courage required to get LASIK. But I’ve been considering it since it was introduced commercially in the 1990s. The surgery is seldom covered by insurance, and exists in the competitive economy typical of most other industries. So people who get LASIK surgery—or for that matter most cosmetic surgeries, dental procedures, or other mostly uninsured treatments—act like consumers. If you do an Internet search today, you can find LASIK procedures quoted as low as $499 per eye—a decline of roughly 80 percent since the procedure was introduced.

The French system requires posting of all charges and allows the doctor, or hospital, to negotiate with the patient without penalty. Such a system would allow competition with newer technology.

How would the health-care reform that’s now taking shape solve these core problems? The Obama administration and Congress are still working out the details, but it looks like this generation of “comprehensive” reform will not address the underlying issues, any more than previous efforts did. Instead it will put yet more patches on the walls of an edifice that is fundamentally unsound—and then build that edifice higher.

A central feature of the reform plan is the expansion of comprehensive health insurance to most of the 46 million Americans who now lack private or public insurance. Whether this would be achieved entirely through the extension of private commercial insurance at government-subsidized rates, or through the creation of a “public option,” perhaps modeled on Medicare, is still being debated.

Regardless, the administration has suggested a cost to taxpayers of $1 trillion to $1.5 trillion over 10 years. That, of course, will mean another $1 trillion or more not spent on other things—environment, education, nutrition, recreation. And if the history of previous attempts to expand the health safety net are any guide, that estimate will prove low.

I’m sure those Obama supporters did not read this article. The uninsured are composed of three groups. One is illegal aliens and I don’t see how that problem is solved. I think Obama’s “public option” would include them since identity checks are not part of the plan. Another third are young healthy workers who choose not to buy insurance. A basic catastrophic policy would be affordable for this group and a mandate for such a policy would work. I don;t blame tem for not wanting to buy the bloated prepaid care style policies that are offered now.

How does he suggest dealing with the cost problem ?

A more consumer-centered health-care system would not rely on a single form of financing for health-care purchases; it would make use of different sorts of financing for different elements of care—with routine care funded largely out of our incomes; major, predictable expenses (including much end-of-life care) funded by savings and credit; and massive, unpredictable expenses funded by insurance.

For years, a number of reformers have advocated a more “consumer-driven” care system—a term coined by the Harvard Business School professor Regina Herzlinger, who has written extensively on the subject. Many different steps could move us toward such a system. Here’s one approach that—although it may sound radical—makes sense to me.

First, we should replace our current web of employer- and government-based insurance with a single program of catastrophic insurance open to all Americans—indeed, all Americans should be required to buy it—with fixed premiums based solely on age. This program would be best run as a single national pool, without underwriting for specific risk factors, and would ultimately replace Medicare, Medicaid, and private insurance. All Americans would be insured against catastrophic illness, throughout their lives.

Proposals for true catastrophic insurance usually founder on the definition of catastrophe. So much of the amount we now spend is dedicated to problems that are considered catastrophic, the argument goes, that a separate catastrophic system is pointless. A typical catastrophic insurance policy today might cover any expenses above, say, $2,000. That threshold is far too low; ultimately, a threshold of $50,000 or more would be better. (Chronic conditions with expected annual costs above some lower threshold would also be covered.) We might consider other mechanisms to keep total costs down: the plan could be required to pay out no more in any year than its available premiums, for instance, with premium increases limited to the general rate of inflation. But the real key would be to restrict the coverage to true catastrophes—if this approach is to work, only a minority of us should ever be beneficiaries.

I absolutely agree with this proposal. A key would be allowing the doctor and patient to negotiate on what the charges not paid by insurance will be. Right now, doctors are banned from charging more than the insurance pays.

What about routine care ?

Every American should be required to maintain an HSA, and contribute a minimum percentage of post-tax income, subject to a floor and a cap in total dollar contributions. The income percentage required should rise over a working life, as wages and wealth typically do.

All noncatastrophic care should eventually be funded out of HSAs. But account-holders should be allowed to withdraw money for any purpose, without penalty, once the funds exceed a ceiling established for each age, and at death any remaining money should be disbursed through inheritance. Our current methods of health-care funding create a “use it or lose it” imperative. This new approach would ensure that families put aside funds for future expenses, but would not force them to spend the funds only on health care.

I hope Obama doesn’t read this. He will need one of those catastrophic policies to deal with the stroke he has. I think these are great ideas for the middle class. The poor, especially the older poor, will have to be subsidized but that is a lesser problem than trying to remake the entire system in one step.

UPDATE: Here are some comments about the VA as a model for reform. I never worked in the VA but know many docs who trained there. This is a good discussion.