Healthcare reform

In my book on the history of medicine I included a chapter on the history that led to the present crisis in health care economics. Basically, there are three general causes of the problem. One is technology. When I was a medical student 40-some years ago, there were no coronary care units, no coronary bypasses, no total hip replacements and life expectancy was about 72 years. When Bismark first established the retirement age at 65 in Germany, that (age 65) was also the average life expectancy. Now it is over 80 years and rising, which leads to the second cause. We have an aging population. Everyone outside of the Muslim world does. Old people need more care and technology has provided the nexus between high technology and age that is breaking the bank.

The third cause is more complex and varies from area to area, depending on the financing of health care. The United States has a mixed system for financing health care. Medicare and Medicaid are government single payer systems for care of the elderly, disabled and the poor (mostly women, children and nursing home residents). In recent years, the mechanism of paying in these systems has changed to the Health Maintenance Organization in many cases. The HMO, as it is abbreviated, is a creature of sociologist and rehabilitation physician, Paul Ellwood.

It would appear that Dr. Paul Ellwood, and his subsequent InterStudy organization, did not expect that the control of their HMOs would be by business executives and corporate shareholders committed only to their own fiduciary motives rather than medical professionals committed to a higher ethic.

The Achilles heel of the HMO system has been the role of perverse incentives. When Paul Ellwood coined the term HMO, he had in mind the fact that fee-for-service medicine creates an incentive for the doctor to do “more” care than the patient really needs in order to increase his own income. John Wennberg, of Dartmouth Medical School, calls this “supplier induced demand.” They did not seem to consider that a powerful HMO has an incentive to do the opposite. In the days before health insurance, the doctor and the patient had a more balanced relationship. Yes, there was a gap in information greater than that between, for example, a car owner and mechanic. Yes, the stakes were higher for the patient than having to buy a new car. Still, the transaction was easier to understand and the incentives were in better balance. Health insurance removed the transaction from the cost-benefit analysis of the patient and doctor to a remote, impersonal third party that, in the early days, had little incentive to interfere. Premiums were often paid by yet another, fourth party, the employer or the government. It is only recently that cost became the driving force it is today.

In his book, “Comeback”, David Frum attributes the distress of the middle class in the US today to the erosion of incomes due to the double whammy of FICA taxes to support programs for the elderly and health insurance premiums deducted by the employer.

In 1992, as President Clinton took office, anticipation was high that a solution was at hand. The Dartmouth people were heavily involved with designing the Clinton Health Plan but the political process went off the rails in an example of how not to do legislative action.

Since the failure of the Clinton attempt at reform, the HMO process has evolved and the only winners appear to be the corporate entities that found how profitable for-profit HMOs could be. They have done this by victimizing both doctors and patients. There has to be a better way.

I’ll post more about this in days to come.

5 Responses to “Healthcare reform”

  1. […] post by A Brief History… Share and Enjoy: These icons link to social bookmarking sites where readers can share and […]

  2. […] post by A Brief History… Share and Enjoy: These icons link to social bookmarking sites where readers can share and […]

  3. doombuggy says:

    >>…he had in mind the fact that fee-for-service medicine creates an incentive for the doctor to do “more” care than the patient really needs in order to increase his own income….They did not seem to consider that a powerful HMO has an incentive to do the opposite.

    I’m wondering if this ‘incentive to do the opposite’ has done anything to reduce health care costs?

  4. It has worked wonderfully to increase the profits of the big for-profit HMOs. Read that LA Times piece.

  5. doombuggy says:

    >>Read that LA Times piece.

    I sometimes wonder if a life of illiteracy would hold more happiness for me.

    >>Dr. Ted Mazer, a San Diego ear, nose and throat specialist, said the time he and colleagues spend fighting for fair and timely payment from UnitedHealth had cut into the time they spent with patients.

    I sometimes find myself defending corporate America, when arguing with Lefties, stressing that corporates deliver the most goods at the lowest prices. Here we have the flip side, where a corporate uses its power to screw people. Ahhgg.

    >>Longtime Chief Executive William McGuire resigned in 2006. Last month, in the first settlement of its kind under post-Enron corporate reforms, he agreed to pay $468 million to avoid trial on charges that he secretly padded his paycheck by manipulating stock options.

    This gives me pause. If he can pay this kind of hush money, how much more does he have? I might vote for Hillary, so she can take the rest away. It makes me think of feudalism, with CEOs like this living in a castle on the hill, with wagon loads of tribute flowing in, while the serfs toil on the countryside. When leadership benefits at this level, no wonder there is not much impetus for change.